- 积分
- 26138
- 威望
- 3588
- 金钱
- 16
- 阅读权限
- 110
- 来自
- 维藤(Witten)
- 在线时间
- 3187 小时
|
10#
发表于 2007-7-1 18:35
| 只看该作者
Notes
(1.) Compare Popper 1972, ch. 5; Krajewski 1977; Birner 1994.
(2.) Except when stated otherwise, in the case of Durkheim pagereferences preceded by DTS are to Durkheim 1893 (1994). References toHayek's three volumes 1973-79 will be given as LLLI, II, or III. Alltranslations from DTS are taken from Durkheim 1964. In the sequel wewill only give the page references.
(3.) Compare for exampleDurkheim, DTS, p. III: "si le vaincu peut se resigner pour un temps aune subordination qu'il est contraint de subir, il ne la consent pas,et, par consequent, elle ne saurait constituer un equilibre stable. Destreves imposees par la violence ne sont jamais que provisoires et nepacifient pas les esprits" ["if the conquered, for a time, must suffersubordination under compulsion, they do not consent to it, andconsequently this cannot constitute a stable equilibrium. Truces,arrived at after violence, are never anything but provisional, andsatisfy no one"; pp. 2-3]; and Hayek LLLII, p. 136: "the attempt tosecure to each what he is thought to deserve, by imposing upon all asystem of common concrete ends towards which their efforts are directedby authority, as socialism aims to do, would be a retrograde step ...."
(4.) Simon 1968.
(5.) Durkheim adds that this explains why we find primitive societies so difficult to understand.
(6.) Or perhaps because of the fact that Durkheim thought his theory tobe more general. In that case, one may suppose that he found theanalysis of markets in political economy satisfactory.
(7.)It would be an exaggeration to speak of Hayek's theory of markets,since he never produced a fully-Hedged and coherent explanation.However, his work of the 1930s and '40s contains the most importantelements for such a theory (compare Birner 1999). Hayek's mostimportant publications dealing with markets and competition are Hayek1937, 1945, 1946, 1947, and 1968.
(8.) A natural extensionof Hayek's ideas on this issue would be to say that this generalavailability of knowledge, together with a constructivist philosophy,has led neoclassical economists to construct their highly idealizedtheory of markets. Indeed, the only economy to which standardneoclassical perfect competition models approximately apply is the nowalmost completely defunct centrally planned socialist or communistsystem.
(9.) Hayek is the first economist to do SO (1937).
(10.) Hayek does not explain what he means by optimum, but the textmakes it clear that it is a situation in which no relevant knowledge isleft unused so that no individual has a motive to change his plan--anindirect way to express a Pareto optimum.
(11.) CompareDesai (1994) for a discussion of the revolutionary character of Hayek'sposing the problem of the division of knowledge.
(12.)Compare also Hayek: "The statement that, if people know everything,they are in equilibrium is true simply because that is how we defineequilibrium' (1937: 46).
(13.) Desai is the only one to notice this aspect of Hayek's analysis of markets. Cp Desai 1994: 41.
(15.) Cp Kirman 1983, 1985, 1991; Gilles 1990 and later published work.
(14.) Cp Richardson 1960 and 1972. Richardson's sources of inspiration are Hayek and Marshall.
(16.) Cp for instance Granovetter 1982, 1985; White 1988; Burt 1992.Among economists, the best known of these is Granovetter, and his work,too, failed to give rise to an economic network tradition.
(17.) Cp Hayek 1937 and 1945.
(18.) Unlike Durkheim, Hayek never formulates a theory of thedevelopment of rational thought. On this compare Birner 1995, 1999.
(19.) This is very similar to Popper's approach to social science.Watkins has coined the fortunate term "negative utilitarianism" forthis.
(20.) Given the fact that Hayek did not himselfcomplete the book, it has to be cited with caution. However, what Hayeksays here is consistent with his neglect of the incentives oncooperation in earlier work, a neglect for which he has been criticizedby, for instance, Witt 1994, Shearmur 1994, and Bianchi 1994.
(21.) "[L]a cooperation, bien loin d'avoir Pu produire Ia societe, ensuppose necessairement le prealable etablissement spontane" (DTS, p.262). ["co-operation, far from having produced society, necessarilysupposes, as preamble, its spontaneous existence."-p. 278].
(22.) For a more extended discussion of this issue in intellectual history cp Birner and Ege 1999.
(23.) Cp Bianchi 1994.
(24.) This can be read as an accurate summary of Durkheim's theory of the division of labor.
(25.) Cp Ege 1995.
(26.) Cp Les regles de la methode sociologique. "Est fait social toutemaniere de faire, fixee ou non, susceptible d'exercer sur l'individuune contrainte exterieure; ou bien encore, qui est generale dansl'etendue d'une societe donnee tout en ayant une existence propre,independente de ses manifestations propres" (p. 14, italics deleted).[In our translation: "Social facts are all types of behaviour, whetheror not laid down in rules, that are capable of acting as an externalconstraint on the individual; or alternatively, that are generaleverywhere in a particular society while having an existence of theirown, independent from their specific manifestations"].
(27.)Cp ITF, p. 15, where Hayek presents the market (order) as a socialtrial-and-error process, where Reason with a capital R exists only byvirtue of many individuals contributing their specific knowledge tosociety in an unplanned manner.
(28.) Both became stimuli tothe development of neural network models and the re-introduction of thestudy of mental processes into psychology that now dominates research.The publication of Hebb's book almost made Hayek give up the project ofpublishing his own. For a discussion of Hayek's psychology and its(paradoxical) place in the whole of his work (to which the text belowrefers briefly), cp Birner 1999a.
(29.) For which the reader may want to consult Birner 1999a.
(30.) Richardson (1960) is an early attempt to include both these factors. Cp also Birner 1999.
(31.) Burt 1992. This analysis can be considered as an extension and aformalization of a type of competition that was analyzed by Mises andHayek. Cp Birner 1996.
(32.) The idea is of course much older. One finds it, for instance, in Menger. Compare Birner 1990.
(33.) Hayek's social theory was strongly influenced by hisneural-network model of the mind; cp. Birner 1996 and 1999a. InDurkheim, too, we find references to physiological psychology (ofWundt), though they have a different function and seem to play amarginal role in the development of his thought (DTS, pp. 322-3).Making comparisons with biology is a tradition that goes at least backto Comte and Spencer. However, like Hayek, Durkheim does not succumb tothe temptation of an organicistic theory of society.
References
Aichian, A. (1950), 'Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory," Journal of Political Economy 58: 211-21
Bianchi, M. (1994), "Hayek's Spontaneous Order: the 'Correct' versusthe 'Corrigible' Society," in Birner and Van Zijp (eds) (1994).
Birner, J. (1990), "A roundabout solution to a fundamental problem inMenger's methodology and beyond," History of Political Economy
__________. (1994). "Idealizations and Theory Development in Economics.Some History and Logic of the Logic of Discovery," in B. Hamminga andN. de Marchi (eds.), Problems of Idealisation in Economics, PoznanStudies
__________. (1996). "Mind, Market and Society.Network Structures in the Work of F. A. Hayek," Working paper.Computable and Experimental Economics Laboratory, University of Trento.
__________. (1999). "Making Markets," in S. C. Dow and P. E.Earl (eds.), Economic Organisation and Economic Knowledge: Essays inHonour of Brian Loasby. Edward Elgar
__________. (1999a) "The Surprising Place of Psychology in the Work of F. A. Hayek," History of Economic ideas.
__________. (1999b) "Hayek, psicologia e economia: elementi per unnuovo programma di ricerca nelle scienze sociali," Nuova Civilta delleMacchine
Birner,J., and Ege, R. (1999). "The moralconsequences of the functionalism of Durkheim and Hayek," paperpresented at the Hayek conference organized by AHTEA, Paris
Birner,J. and van Zijp, R. (eds) (1994). Hayek, Co-ordination andEvolution; His Legacy in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and theHistory of Ideas. London: Routledge
Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural Holes. The Social Structure of Competition, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Desai, M. (1994). "Equilibrium, Expectations and Knowledge," in Birner and Van Zijp (eds)
Dow, S. C., and Earl, P. E. (eds) (1999) Economic Organisation andEconomic Knowledge: Essays in Honour of Brian Loasby. Edward Elgar
Durkheim, E. ([1893]) 1978). De la division du travail social. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France
Durkheim, E. (1893a), "Note sur la definition du socialisme," Revue Philosophique
Durkheim, E. (1895/1937), Les regles de la methode sociologique, Paris, Presses Universitaires de France (1997)
Durkheim, E. (1964), The Division of Labour in Society, translated byGeorge Simpson, New York, The Free Press, and London,Collier-Macmillan, 7th Printing, 1969
Ege, R. (1995). "Emergence du marche concurrentiel et evolutionnisme chez Hayek," Revue Economique
Gilles, R. P. (1990). Core and Equilibria of Socially StructuredEconomies; The Modelling of Social Constraints in Economic Behavior.Ph.D. thesis, University of Tilburg.
Granovetter, M, (1982)."The Strength of Weak Ties; A Network Theory Revisited," AmericanJournal of Sociology, 78: 1360-80.
__________. (1985)."Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness," inGranovetter and Swedberg (eds) (1992).
Granovetter, M. and Swedberg, R. (eds). (1992). The Sociology of Economic Life. Boulder, CO, Westview Press.
Hayek, F. A. (1937), "Economics and Knowledge," in Hayek (1949)
Hayek, F. A. (1945), "The Use of Knowledge in Society," in Hayek (1949).
Hayek, F. A. (1946), "The Meaning of Competition," in Hayek (1949).
Hayek, F. A. (1947), ""Free Enterprise" and Competitive Order," in Hayek (1949).
Hayek, F. A. (1949), Individualism and Economic Order. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul
F. A. Hayek (1952), The Sensory Order, Chicago, Ill.: Chicago University Press.
F. A. Hayek (1955), The Counterrevolution of Science, Glencoe: The Free Press
Hayek, F. A. (1960) The Constitution of Liberty, London, Routledge & Kegan Paul
Hayek, F. A. (1968), "Competition as a Discovery Procedure," in Hayek (1978).
F. A. Hayek, (1969), "The Primacy of the Abstract," in Hayek (1978)
Hayek, F. A. (1973-79) Law, Legislation and Liberty (3 vols), London,Routledge & Kegan Paul; quoted as LLLI, II, or III
Hayek, F. A. (1978). New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics andthe History of Ideas. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Hayek, F. A. (1988) The Fatal Conceit, London, Routledge; quoted as FC
Hermann-Pillath, C. (1994). "Evolutionary Rationality, 'HomoEconomicus,' and the Foundations of Social Order," Journal of Socialand Evolutionary Systems 17(1)
Jackendoff, J. (1989). Consciousness and the Computational Mind. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Kirman, A. (1983), "Communication in Markets: A Suggested Approach," Economics Letters, 12: 101-8.
__________. (1985). "Organisation et communication dans les marches," Economie qppliquee 3: 597-609.
__________. (1991). "Information, communication et coordination," Economie appliquee, XLIV: 105-24.
Krajewski, W. (1977). Correspondence principle and growth of science. Dordrecht: Reidel
Popper, K. R. (1972). Objective Knowledge. Routledge
Richardson, G. B. (1960). Information and Investment; A Study in theWorking of the Competitive Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Richardson, S. B. (1972) "The Organisation of Industry," Economic Journal
Shearmur, J. (1994), "Hayek and the Case for Markets," in Birner and Van Zijp
Simon, H. (1968). The Sciences of the Artificial. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Witt, U. (1994). "The Theory of Societal Evolution: Hayek's Unfinished Legacy," in Birner and Van Zijp |
|